If you are a beginner and have just started to study production theories of microeconomics, so then you are in the right place to start from. After studying this article, you will learn the concepts of production, production function, and the concepts of total, average, and marginal product and their relationships. Moreover, you will also get to know types of production functions based on time, variability of factor proportion, and factor substitutability (linearly homogeneous production function, Cobb-Douglas production function, and CES production function) in a clear-cut way.

The theory of production is a very crucial subject matter in the field of economics. And, production theories heavily rely on the concept of production and production function. It would be more fruitful to understand the precise concept of the terms production and production function before we attempt to study the production theories, that are extensively used in the field of economics. In this scenario, below mentioned sections try to elaborate on these concepts one after another.

Concept of Production and Production Function

In the economic profession, production refers to the creation of utility. The creation of utility is possible through the conversion of factor inputs into the output, and this job is done by the production function. Inputs that are used in the production are factors of production or simply, factor inputs. The production function incorporates factor inputs in the production process and yields the output. Hence, the production function is the process by which inputs are converted into output. In other words, production function is defined as the technical or engineering relationship between factor inputs and outputs. Mathematically, it is expressed as:

Q = f (K, L, M, N, …, Z) … … … (I),

where, ‘f’ denotes the functional relation between output, Q, and other factors of production like capital, labor, land, raw material, energy, entrepreneur, technology, and so on.

However, in modern economics, labor and capital are only two dominant factors of production. Economists overlook other factors of production to produce a basic economic framework or economic model with ease of exposition. Accordingly, the usable production function shall revert to

Q = f (K, L) … … … (II),

where notations stand for their usual meaning. Given the values of K and L, they are referred to as exogenous variables i.e. their values are taken as given. Unlikely, Q is called endogenous i.e. whose value depends on other variables and varies over time. In addition, the production function also equally represents the technology of production. The basic economic theory of production assumes only the efficient method of production because an inefficient method of production will not be used by a rational producer.

Total, Average, and Marginal Concepts of Production

We need some preliminary concepts while studying the production theory. They are total products and per-unit products. The total product of capital (TPK) and total product of Labor (TPL) are the total product concepts; and the marginal product of capital (MPK), the marginal product of Labor (MPL), the average product of capital (APK) and average product of Labor (APL) are the per unit product concepts. We elaborate on these concepts in terms of labor, which equally applies in terms of capital as well.

Total Product

The total product of labor is the aggregate amount of output produced by the total labor units used in the production. Alternatively, TPL is the sum of marginal products of labor i.e. TPL = MPL (1) + MPL (2) + MPL (3) + … + MPL (n-1) + MPL (n), where MPL (n) is the marginal product of labor from an nth unit of labor.

Average Product of Labor

It is the output per unit of labor (APL) and is obtained by dividing the total product of labor (TPL) by the total number of labor (L) i.e. APL = TPL /L. In the figure presented below, average products of labor at points B and C are given by the slopes of line segments OB and OC respectively.

Marginal Product of Labor

It is the extra unit of output produced by employing one additional unit of labor. Put another way, it is the change in TPL due to a change in one extra unit of labor i.e.

MPL= ΔTPL / ΔL

where Δ shows the change in the respective variables (ΔL is always 1 because labor unit changes one by one i.e. 1, 2, 3… n-1, n person). This is a per-unit production because the marginal refers to the yields from the one additional factor unit. That means we are talking about calculating marginal product from tabular data (also called discrete data), and such calculation of marginal product is called arc marginal product because it measures marginal product between two points. However, the following figure measures point marginal product of labor at points A and C, given by the slope of respective tangents, as they measure the marginal product at those points.

Graphically,

Relationships between total product, average product and marginal product of labor

Relationship between MPL and TPL

hen MPL keeps on increasing, TPL increases at an increasing rate; when MPL remains constant, TPL increases at a constant rate; when MPL decreases, TPL increases at a decreasing rate; when MPL is zero, TPL remains constant; and when MPL is negative, TPL decreases.

Relationship between MPL and APL

When MPL > APL, APL increases; when MPL = APL, APL remains constant; when MPL < APL, APL decreases.

In the subsequent section, we will examine the types of production functions.

Long-run vs Short-run Production Function

What separates the long run from the short run in the economic profession? No doubt, the answer is the time a variable could take to vary. In this regard, factors of production are classified into long-run and short-run based on the variability i.e. time they take to be variable. Doing this is beneficial for us to thoroughly examine and understand the theories of production.

Short-run in economics is a time interval, in which we cannot even change a single factor input. This way a production function is short-run when at least one-factor input cannot be changed during the period. In other terms, when not all factors of production are variable then a production function is short-run, and called short-run production function. Hence, at least one-factor input must be fixed in the short-run production function.

On the other hand, all the factor inputs are variable in the long-run production function. Long-run is defined as the period in which all factor inputs, that are included in the production function, can be changed. However, there is no specific law that stipulates the short- and long-run. It is all about the theory, but in practice, it depends on the nature of production activity that determines short- and long-run. That is why, the practical thinking of economists is that the long run is a planning period in which decisions regarding investment in new plants and machinery can be undertaken, whereas the short run involves the operations from existing plants and machinery.

Fixed vs Variable Proportion Production Function

Let us first understand the concept of proportion before starting the topic. Proportion refers to the equality of two ratios, that is,  connecting two ratios by an equality sign results in proportion. This way ratios are the integral parts of proportion, and we mean proportion here to refer to the equality of different capital-labor ratios.

Also, one more thing to consider here is a term called technical coefficients of production, which is the amount of factor inputs required to produce a certain commodity. For example, suppose that it needs 10 units of capital to produce 50 units of a particular commodity, then the technical coefficient of capital for production is 0.2. If we were to express it on a percentage basis, it would require 20 percent capital to produce 50 units of commodity.

Now that we define proportion and technical coefficients of production, it is time to describe fixed and variable proportion production functions. Whether the production function is variable or fixed proportion depends on the technical coefficients of production. If technical coefficients of factors are constant, then the production function is fixed or constant proportion production function, otherwise, variable proportion production function.

In a fixed constant proportion production function, the capital-labor ratio remains fixed no matter how large the scale of production is, as opposed to a variable proportion production function. Likewise, there is zero marginal rate of technical substitution between factor inputs -capital and labor- in fixed or constant proportion production function, which means factors are perfect complements.  On the other hand, there might be limited factor substitutability or perfect substitutes in the case of variable proportion production function.

Linearly Homogeneous Production Function

If the multiplication of each factor input of a production function by a constant ‘j’ leads to the multiplication of output by jr, then the production function is said to be homogeneous of degree r. 

Mathematically, the general homogeneous production function of degree r is written as:

jr Q= F(jL, jK) where j, r > 0  …………………. (III)

where Q is output, L is labor, K is capital, and j and r are constants greater than zero. However, j and r can take any value,  but we take these values as positive from the aspect of economic variables which are rarely negatives.

When the value of r in equation (III) is 1, then the homogeneous production function is of first degree, which is also the linearly homogeneous production function we refer to. That means  jQ= F(jL, jK) is a linearly homogeneous production function and implies that multiplying factor inputs by constant j results in the multiplication of output by the same constant j. Thus it shows the constant returns to scale.

Characteristics of Homogeneous Production Function

General homogeneous production function jr Q= F(jL, jK) exhibits the following characteristics based on the value of r. 

If r = 1, it implies constant returns to scale. In such a case, the production function is said to be linearly homogeneous of the first order.

If r > 1, it implies increasing returns to scale.

If r < 1, it implies decreasing returns to scale.

Due to its simplicity and good approximation of real-world situations, this production function is widely used in linear programming and input-output models.

Cobb-Douglas Production Function

This very famous Cobb-Douglas production function is a long-run production function and is the result of the combined efforts of professor of economics cum U.S. senator Paul Douglas and mathematician Charles Cobb. Douglas observed U.S. data and found that the shares of national income to labor and capital remained almost constant over the long period. Put another way, despite continuous growth in national income, a proportionate share of labor and capital to national income almost grew at a constant rate. The very fact is depicted in the special case of the Cobb-Douglas production function.

Mathematically, the general Cobb-Douglas production function is written as:

Q= F(L,K) = A Kα Lβ where A, α, β > 0 …………………. (IV)

where Q is output, α is output elasticity of capital, β is output elasticity of labor, and A is productivity or total factor productivity measuring the productivity of production function or technology or factor inputs in total. And, all of these parameters are positive. If the production technique advances, it raises the value of the productivity parameter, A. Raising the value of total factor productivity, A, equally means that productivity of both labor and capital has increased.

The parameters α and β, which also measure the shares of national income to capital and labor, are distribution parameters. That is parameters α and β measure the contribution of capital and labor to total production or national income. Note that the usage of the Cobb-Douglas production function here is in a macro sense, that’s why it is often called an aggregate production function. However, it can be used in the micro sense as well.

Characteristics of Cobb-Douglas Production Function

Let’s observe the Cobb-Douglas production function Q = A Kα Lβ supposing that we change capital and labor by some constant multiple of λ, which results in the right side of the function as:

A (λK)α (λL)β = λα+β A Kα Lβ = λα+β . Q

which implies that by increasing the factor inputs by a multiple of some constant λ, output increases by the multiple of λα+β. That means coefficient λα+β shows the joint contribution of capital and labor to output. More specifically, coefficient α+β is a measure of returns to scale. You can find more information on the law of returns to scale.

If α+β = 1, it implies constant returns to scale. In such a case, the production function is said to be linearly homogeneous of first order.

If α+β > 1, it implies increasing returns to scale.

If α+β < 1, it implies decreasing returns to scale.

In the case of a linearly homogeneous production function of the first order, the following features hold:

  • Cobb-Douglas production function exhibits constant returns to scale. That means doubling the factor inputs doubles the output by the same proportion.
  • It demonstrates diminishing returns i.e. marginal product of factor diminishes. More precisely, the marginal product of a factor input decreases as it is used more and more, holding constant the other factor inputs.
  • It exhibits the unit elasticity of factor substitution (For more read here).

Initially, the Cobb-Douglas production was used in the manufacturing industry. Now, it is widely used in empirical studies as well.

CES Production Function

CES stands for constant elasticity of substitution. This latest CES production function is due to the joint effort of Arrow Chenery, Minhas, and Solow. This CES production function is a more general production function that yields the constant elasticity of factor substitution other than 1.

Mathematically, the general CES production function is written as:

Q= A[?K-ρ + (1-?)L-ρ]-1/ρ where A > 0, 0<?<1, -1<ρ≠0 ………………. (V)

where Q is output, L is labor, K is Capital, and A is the efficiency parameter serving as a state of technology as A in Cobb-Douglas production function? is a distribution parameter showing relative factor shares as α and β in the Cobb-Douglas production function, and ρ is the substitution parameter that has no counterpart in Cobb-Douglas production and is a determinant of constant elasticity of substitution in the CES production function.

The elasticity of substitution between factors (σ) is given by 1/(1+ρ) in the CES production function i.e. σ = 1/(1+ρ).

Characteristics of CES Production Function

CES production function is linearly homogeneous and exhibits constant returns to scale. Based on the value of ρ, it produces the following results for σ :

When -1<ρ<0, then σ >1.
When ρ = 0, then σ = 1.
When 0< ρ < ∞, then σ < 1.

Cobb-Douglas production function is a special case of CES production function when there is unitary elasticity of substitution. This means that the linearly homogeneous CES production function is a Cobb-Douglas production function producing constant returns to scale.

Tagged

Author

TopicBin Contribution: 29 articles Total articles contributed

TopicBin is a publishing platform for authors, and it is promoted by an instructor, web developer and commercial banker. It aims to deliver conceptual articles related to economics, banking, finance, management and technical streams.

More Articles
By TopicBin . Updated . 4 min read
By TopicBin . Updated . 4 min read
By TopicBin . Updated . 9 min read

Leave a Reply